As outlined in previous posts, the creditors face two key issues with the restructuring:
- Obligor Attitude: If there are not already serious concerns about the obligor’s integrity and willingness to pay, then there should be. The situation is similar to that of The Investment Dar Kuwait. Back when it became evident that TID was headed for a restructuring, if not the shoals, its creditors petitioned the Central Bank of Kuwait to appoint an official “minder” to keep an eye on—or more accurately to “control”— TID’s management. CBK did not. By contrast creditors did not ask for one in the Global Investment House (Kuwait) restructuring a similarly uncertain large ticket exercise. As DG is a commercial company and not a financial institution, there’s not even the extremely slim possibility of CBUAE intervention. Creditors are “on their own”. That has important consequences for what they should do.
- Obligor Aptitude: Glacially slow collection of receivables and an apparent chronic weakness in operating cashflow indicate that the obligor is unlikely to repay principal and interest within the proposed five-year tenor. Factors largely outside DG’s control. The path was cast when DG embarked on its business in Iraq and Egypt. Given these facts, creditors are likely to find themselves in another restructuring “adventure” with DG in five years’ time. Therefore, minimizing that future exposure should be a key goal.
Что делать?
In framing this post, AA looked to inspiration from other authors who wrote similarly titled pieces, though hopefully this post is free from excessive utopianism. As you'll notice one such author is missing. I believe he was in heated exchange on call-in program with the Governor of New Jersey when I called.
In any case, here's are potential steps that AA believes creditors need to take based on the assessment that protection of creditor interests requires measures beyond
the usual ones in a restructuring.
- Legal steps –recast the deal or elements of the deal to reduce/eliminate exposure to Abu Yusuf-ery legal maneuvering by the obligor. While this is an important step, it will not be sufficient to protect creditors’ interests.
- Collateral – get more and to the extent possible, take possession now rather than relying on the exercise of legal rights to deliver it later when Abu Yusuf may have come up with even more clever arguments.
- Amortization – use interim scheduled principal repayments plus a cash sweep to achieve reductions. With DG’s weak/uncertain cashflow getting dollars now is wiser than waiting five-years as the past ten years unequivocally demonstrate.
- Tenors – Shorten to keep DG’s and your minds focused on repayment. A five year bullet moves the payment far enough into the future that focus is lost: repayment is a lower priority, particularly for DG.
Legal
Transaction documents are meant not only
to set forth the obligations and rights of both parties so there is no
ambiguity, but also to provide protection by providing recourse through court ordered enforcement of the agreement if one party cannot
fulfill its contractual obligations or decides not to. DG’s
maneuver in Sharjah and other courts to declare the Sukuk contract “illegal and
unenforceable” shows the practical limits of that strategy.
One response would be to change the form of
the replacement contract. If “Islamic”
transactions are uncertain, then a conventional (non-Shari’ah) transaction
would seem preferable. If a starving
Muslim may eat a ham sandwich in order to avoid death, then it seems to me that
if confronted with an obligor that may not be trustworthy as originally assumed and uncertain protection
from the courts, a Muslim creditor could legitimately change the form of
contract to a non-halal one. This is
important because as shown with the English and BVI courts actions, non-GCC
courts are likely to show deference at least initially to areas beyond their
competence, e.g., the Shari’ah.
A less severe approach would be to recast the
debt obligation into another form of “Islamic” transaction as discussed
below. Perhaps, the transaction could be
split into two? One tranche for only
principal repayments in which case Shari’ah or non-Shari’ah distinctions might
not apply. Or in other words, the first tranche would be both. The second an Islamic structure for "profit" (interest), hopefully limiting opportunities for future Abu Yusuf-ery. Dealing with default interest could be
difficult, but creditors are going to have to make some hard tradeoffs
following their initial and unfortunate underwriting decision. The ability to ensure cross default would be another key consideration with this no doubt utopian strategy.
Other actions would be to ensure that
entities critical to the success of repayment were incorporated and active in
jurisdictions believed to be more likely to give the creditors a fair shake
rather than relying on the uncertain existence of a fair shakyh in local GCC jurisdictions. Reducing as much as possible the impact of
local law on the transaction would be ideal.
Alternatively, could the DIFC be the jurisdiction for the restructuring
suitably structured as an offshore transaction?
But such steps are unlikely to
be definitive, even if they are theoretically possible.
In particular, Argentina’s or the Arab Bank’s recent unhappy
experiences in US courts should suggest more than abundance of caution is
warranted with reliance on legal jurisdictions as providing a “fair shake”.
Collateral
On the theory that the “old” deal is dead, then a new deal needs to
be struck. So the door is potentially
open to new terms.
It’s often said
that possession is nine tenths of the law.
This should be a guiding principal for the creditors.
A wise move would
be what is in effect a pre-emptive exercise of collateral/security rights. That
argues for the creditors getting possession/ownership of collateral now
to be returned upon full repayment. Transfers of ownership would take place at the
inception of the transaction not after a default occurs and potentially lengthy
and uncertain legal proceedings are concluded.
A potential replacement structure
is a sale/leaseback with DG responsible for operations, capex, insurance, third
party liabilities, etc. DG would sell
these assets (by selling the stock in the companies) to the existing Sukuk
holders. The holders would then lease the
assets to DG for an x-year period. No
cash would change hands as the “proceeds” of the sale/leaseback would serve to
retire the existing obligation. Sukuk repayment
would come from lease payments where perhaps a fixed profit rate would pose
less of a problem if Shari’ah structures were chosen. Upon its successful retirement of the
sale/leaseback transaction, DG would have a bargain purchase option to
reacquire the assets.
Additional collateral. Zora is
now free from debt and generating cash. It is perhaps the most saleable of DG’s
assets. More (stale) receivables,
assignments of proceeds from arbitral awards, ownership of the holding and
operating companies for Egypt and the KRG. But unless Dana Gas Ventures BVI owns shares in Pearl, then the KRG operations are not part of the Trust Assets.
Creditors can expect a robust reaction from DG based on the Trust Assets (TA) being the only security offered. So obtaining new collateral not related to the original TA will be extremely difficult.
If no new collateral can be obtained, then the
creditors should take possession of the Trust Assets as outlined above. If the lessee fails to pay, then the bargain
purchase option would be invalid. The assets could be sold to third parties in
whole or part.Or investment “adventure” in Egypt
or the KRG. Bon chance! Of course, DG or its
shareholders could be given pre-emptive rights in any asset sales.
Principal Reduction – Amortization
As indicated in my earlier post, the
Company’s cashflow is highly unlikely to enable it to retire the debt over the
mooted five-year tenor. Creditors could rely as they have over the past ten
years on the Company’s promise for principal payment at the end of the
next five-years bolstered by no doubt a rosy projection.
Or they could more wisely include binding
(such as one can bind DG) requirements for principal repayments.
With DG’s
uncertain cashflow, it’s hard to come up with repayment scenarios. But that doesn’t mean that the new deal
cannot contain some required interim principal repayments before the
final principal balloon payment at maturity.
A key problem with this approach is that it requires faith in DG’s
compliance. Fool me once shame on you.
Fool me thrice – we’ll you know the rest.
A more prudent option would be to include a cash sweep with the required
principal payment structure. As cash
came into a newly established concentration account controlled by the
security agent (both account and security agent located in a more reasonable
jurisdiction), the cash would be divided by the security agent according to a
pre-agreed formula. This mechanism
ensures (subject to there being a cashflow) that creditors are not forgotten.
Cashflow for the creditors under the sweep would be directed first to scheduled
principal payments and then to prepayments.
That is, the sweep should not be limited to only the scheduled payments,
but to as much as can be taken limited only by the outstanding debt amount. The
point is get the cash now not later. Creditors would be wise to eliminate
prepayment penalties as debt collection is the key issue they face.
There
is another very real benefit to this arrangement. Just as taking ownership of collateral at the
inception of the deal makes it difficult for DG to frustrate creditor rights so
does a cash sweep. Under the cash sweep cash would be given to creditors on an
ongoing basis as soon as practical after it were received in the concentration
account. Creditors would immediately
apply the cash against principal due. It
should be more difficult for DG to later clawback the cash already “swept” to
the creditors compared to making some bogus assertion about the transaction
becoming invalid due to changing interpretations and then not paying.
Shorter Tenor
Restructuring at the same or a longer
tenor defers the day of reckoning far into the future, particularly if an
inadvisable bullet structure is used.
Far enough so that it’s not a priority for either. To avoid this unhappy outcome the maturity of the debt should be shortened. The debt could be divided into tranches
(cross default protected) with a maturity ladder, i.e., 1, 2, 3, 4, 5 years. Or left as a single amount with 2 or 2.5 year
maturity. This would keep the pressure
on DG and hopefully prevent the creditors from lapsing into unwarranted
somnolescence.
The shorter maturities
would offer creditors the opportunity to reopen the debt to impose additional terms more frequently as it is highly likely that DG will require more than five
years to repay the debt, absent a miracle. And as AA was once told by a local GCC banker, the only "miracles" in Islam occur in the financial statements of Islamic financiers.
No comments:
Post a Comment